Ana Marie Cox
The Rise of the Corporate University
The 1960s stand as the last decade when big questions were raised about
the modern university. Students who were starting to congeal into the New
Left protested the university’s collusion with government and defense
corporations as the Vietnam War raged on. Intellectuals like Paul Goodman
defended the free-speech movement (FSM) at the University of California-
Berkeley, arguing for a renewal of the medieval conception of the university
as a “community of scholars” capable of governing itself and resisting outside
forces. As a key leader of and spokesperson for the FSM, Mario Savio
famously strode onto the top of a policeman’s car to give a ringing protest
speech against the “multiversity.” As Savio saw it, the vision of the university
most fervently advocated by Clark Kerr, the president of California’s entire
university system, represented “the greatest problem of our nation—
depersonalized, unresponsive bureaucracy.” Its enormous size, its conformity,
its tendency to churn out students like products on a factory line—all these
features of the modern university symbolized how America was “becoming
ever more the utopia of sterilized, automated contentment.”1
Savio’s speech captured the sensibility behind so much of the New Left’s
earlier protest against the university. The complaint centered on conformity
and boredom, attempting to renew an existential vision of politics as resistance
and rebellion. The business world that awaited students after leaving the
university was dull and complacent. As Savio explained, “The university is
well-structured, well tooled, to turn out people with all the sharp edges worn
off.”2 Students were learning the routines of the “organization man”—the
term William Whyte had used during the 1950s to describe corporate
employees who worked for the large, faceless, bureaucratic corporations that
came to dominate the American economy. Kerr himself, as one historian
points out, was a “man of liberal, mildly social democratic views” who had
wanted to make the university serve society.3 He was no reactionary but
rather a prominent labor economist and a liberal. Nonetheless, as New Left
activists saw it, he had made his pact with the large bureaucratic structures in
the American economy. Savio, in attacking Kerr, helped codify for the baby
boom generation the problem of the “multiversity” and the nature of
corporate work—bureaucratic, boring, stifling, dull.
Much has changed since that time, not the least the nature of corporate
life. The organization man is now a thing of the past. Business isn’t interested
in stability or long-term careers.4 Flexibility, mobility, empowerment, dynamic
change—these are the terms that management theorists speak of today. It is
with good reason that Daniel Pink opens his book, Free Agent Nation, with a
section titled “Bye, Bye, Organization Guy.” At the high end of the corporate
world, people speak of consultancies; at the low end, of temping. What
both have in common is an end to stability. The man in the gray flannel
suit training it home at 5 P.M. every day has been replaced by the superhip
consultant chatting on her cell phone while stuck in traffic at 8 P.M. The
world of the baby boomers has disappeared, replaced by the world of
Generation X—perhaps better termed the “contingent labor generation.”
Universities have changed with this world. They no longer collude with
big business; they have become increasingly identical to business. The wall
between the two has grown thin. Universities have always been a party to
job training—from the turn-of-the century demand for managerial professionals
to the desire for safe “organization men” in Savio’s time and the Internet
wizards of our own time. But now corporations want to run the show
themselves, or at least have more direct say in the matter. As Ana Marie Cox
explains in chapter 1, many want “just-in-time knowledge”—that is, the skills
necessary for the job at hand, rather than basic underlying skills. Take the
example of Digipen Institute of Technology. Licensed by the state of
Washington to grant a baccalaureate of science in “Real Time Interactive
Simulation,” this new higher education institution is run by Nintendo
Corporation. A journalist points out, “Students take no humanities or social
science courses whatsoever.”5 That’s because those things are superfluous for
the needs of the Nintendo Corporation. What’s necessary is what’s good for
the bottom line—that is, education for the immediate tasks at hand.
What is new about today’s university is not only that it serves the
corporation—for it always has done that—but that it emulates it. This is the
most essential feature of the new university that the authors discuss here.
Universities now see the potential for profit; they import managerial
techniques from corporations; they use new technologies by which
administrators assume more control over professors’ labor; they “temp”
their workforce. Perhaps the only thing that the university hasn’t done that
the corporation has is move all over the globe. After all, many universities
are rooted in a specific city or town. Needless to say, via new computer
technologies, they have scrambled across the globe in search of new students,
all the while driven by the search for more profits.
What the authors in this section make clear is just how deeply these
developments have already reshaped the contemporary university. The first
stories heard about Phoenix University made it sound quirky and odd: a
university without any campus that traded on the stock market. What Ana
Marie Cox shows here is just how advanced the for-profit sector in higher
education has become, as witnessed in massive growth and a mimic pattern
among nonprofit universities. David Noble points out just how quickly
numerous universities have taken up the questionable practice of distance
education. Denise Tanguay shows that even at universities with faculty unions,
merit pay and other corporate work schemes have skyrocketed. And Benjamin
Johnson shows that most attempts to measure the amount of teaching done
by underpaid graduate students, adjuncts, and postdocs have vastly
underestimated the extent and effects of such teaching.
What shapes these authors’ understanding of the problems they discuss
is firsthand experience—Cox from her years as a journalist, Noble in his
struggles against distance learning at numerous universities, Tanguay in her
work for the American Association of University Professors (AAUP), and
Johnson in his work to organize Yale graduate students. Though they are
dispassionate—in the best sense of that term—they are also committed to
working on the issues they document and discuss.
Like the New Left before them, the authors here also want to initiate a
debate about the broader purposes of higher education. They aren’t content
simply to document the rise of corporate practices but want to ask a bigger
question: What exactly is the purpose of education? Underlying their essays
is a major assumption about education in today’s society: It should be
democratic in the deepest and richest sense of that term. In this day and age,
that makes them conservative to large extent (which might sound slightly
odd, since all of them support unionization). For instance, they all imply that
education should be wedded to a classical view of citizenship—that is, the
cultivation of a well-rounded individual not only capable of the private pursuit
of well-being but also capable of “culture” (thinking critically and appreciating
works of imagination) and such skills of democracy as debating and contributing
to public decision making. None of them cites him, but there seems almost a
harkening back to Thomas Jefferson’s ideal of democratic education. What
worries these authors is that by adopting corporate practices and looking
only at the short term, we will shed the democratic promise of education: to
educate citizens for the responsibilities of selfgovernment.
By showing how the democratic ideal of education is threatened, these
authors make clear the need for spheres of life that are not subservient to
market pressures. Education must be allowed to flourish without the bottom
line entering into each and every decision. The relationship between students
and teachers—the give-and-take of dialogue and learning—cannot be
commodified without losing something. By making this clear, the authors in
this section push the debate about the future of higher education a step
forward.
STEAL THIS UNIVERSITY:
THE RISE OF THE CORPORATE UNIVERSITY
AND THE ACADEMIC LABOR MOVEMENT
Edited by Benjamin Johnson,
Patrick Kavanagh, and Kevin Mattson
CHAPTER 1
None of Your Business
The Rise of the University of Phoenix and
For-Profit Education—and Why
It Will Fail Us All
Ana Marie Cox
Most discussions of for-profit higher education rely on the simple shock
value of presenting education as a business to get readers’ attention. Calling
students “customers,” not bothering with the humanities, skipping the physical
accoutrements that make college the ivy-walled American dream—these
are the characteristics editorial writers and reporters focus on when they
want to throw harsh light onto the dark specter of higher education as a
growth industry. Lost in that showman’s spotlight, however, is an even scarier
fact: the specter is getting closer. In the past twenty years, more than 500
new for-profit colleges and universities have opened their doors—at the four-
year level, for-profits have increased their numbers from 18 to 192.1 A
quarter of the $750 billion spent each year on higher education stems from
private, proprietary investment.2 Analysts predict this segment will grow by
about 20 percent a year, until it finally displaces nonprofit education—or what
for-profit educators call the “last remaining government monopoly in the
world.”3 Today, forty for-profit education ventures trade publicly, up from
one decade ago. We’ve moved beyond the moment when the idea of selling
stock in a university was a laughable exception to the rule.
No other company epitomizes this exponential growth like the University
of Phoenix and its parent company, the Apollo Group. Perhaps one of the
most dramatic success stories of the ’90s “long boom,” and certainly one of
the only success stories not interrupted by the dot.bomb implosion, Phoenix
recently outpaced New York University to become the largest private
university in the country. From its start in 1975 as a small, single-campus
operation offering only a degree in business, Phoenix now grants bachelor’s,
master’s, and even doctorates in such high-demand fields as nursing, teaching,
and managing of information systems. It has grown to enroll more than
one hundred thousand students on 116 campuses and “learning centers”
in twenty-two states and around the world; an additional thirtyseven
thousand students participate in its online component, touted as a highly
efficient “computerized educational delivery system.”4 John Sperling, the
founder of the University of Phoenix, told the Financial Times that his school
was “the Cadillac of higher education.”5 At the same time, Peter Sperling,
son of John, told the Independent, “McDonald’s has not aspired to be Maxim’s,
but you know you’re going to get a good, healthy meal.”6 One could quibble
with the aptness of the specific analogies, but the general metaphor is dead-
on: Phoenix has done more than almost any other education enterprise to
shift the meaning of college from that of a process one goes through to a
product one buys.
In Higher Ed, Inc., former DeVry Institute administrator Steve Ruch lays
out the recipe for the success of his own leading institution as well as
Phoenix and most other for-profits:
Imagine a regionally accredited university with a tightly focused
mission of preparing students for the world of work. Imagine that
this institution offers undergraduate and graduate degree programs
only in fields for which there is high marketplace demand. In
fields for which there is little or no market demand, by either
stud ents or employers, degree programs are not offered. Imagine
also that this university runs year-round, fully utilizing its facilities
during the day, evening, and weekends throughout the whole year.
The fulltime faculty do not have tenure, and 90 percent of them
are fully deployed to teach. The energy of this institution…is focused
primarily on the success and satisfaction of its students.7
One might also imagine that this institution doesn’t have a library, insurance
plans, dormitories, student groups, or liberal arts majors as is the case with
most for-profits. To this efficient mix, Phoenix adds some specific innovations.
The company owns no property whatsoever (its classes—scheduled mostly in
the evening—are often held in the empty rooms of nearby traditional schools).
Phoenix avoids the traditional high default rate on student loans that has
traditionally plagued many proprietary institutions by enrolling only working
students 23 or older, most of whose employers gen erally subsidize the tuition.
Phoenix ensures employers’ continued support by allowing companies to tailor
these students’ curricula to their needs. And in order to optimize its access to
government money, Phoenix has until recently identified online students as
residential students in applications for federal student aid. The school has also
structured schedules so that up to half of any given course’s class time may
proceed without an instructor present.
These last two techniques aren’t legal (Phoenix was fined more than $6
million by the Department of Education in 1999 and ordered to return the
aid it received through false reports), but all of them have been very
lucrative.8 The Apollo Group’s gross annual earnings have almost doubled
in just the past three years, climbing from $384 million in 1998 to $769
million in 2001.9 Even in the current, rather dim economic environment,
industry insiders have pegged Phoenix and the Apollo Group as the “fastestgrowing,
high-quality companies in the sector.”10 This kind of momentum
demonstrates that we can no longer wonder “what if” for-profits steal
students from traditional schools. The question today is “What now?”
Phoenix Ascending
John Sperling is a former professor at the University of California at San
Jose and a graduate of Reed College (a leading liberal arts college) and
Cambridge University. Sperling’s academic background, full of the kind of
stuffiness and name-brand cachet associated with traditional educators, does
not suggest the man he has become. The man who would go to the helm of
the largest university in the country without a tenure system, much less
any form of collective bargaining, was once a union organizer, president of
his local American Federation of Teachers (AFT) branch and a member of
its national board. Sperling has written hymns of praise about his graduate
student days at the University of the California at Berkeley, where “we
honed our academic skills by expounding and arguing theory, fact, and
fiction—it was a moveable intellectual feast.”11 At the same time, he has
created an approach to education centered exclusively on the development
of “employability,” tailoring his courses to the demands of companies who
pay for their workforce’s schooling. And the man who developed the
prototype of Phoenix using hundreds of thousands of dollars in federal
research grants is now one of the most vocal proponents for holding nonprofit
colleges “accountable” for meeting specific “educational outcomes” and
accuses traditional institutions of wasting taxpayer dollars.
Since founding the University of Phoenix, Sperling has put much of his
considerable personal fortune (which now stands at more than $1 billion)
toward pet projects that range from the mildly amusing to the outright
heretical. For years, Sperling has been the primary investor in Seafire International,
a company he founded to develop saltwater agriculture. In the
late 1990s, Sperling teamed up with fellow multimillionaire George Soros
in a campaign to legalize marijuana, a project that continues to this day. An
interest in “life extension” prompted the formation of the Kronos Group,
a New Age medical center dedicated to “Clinical Age Management.”
Sperling’s most infamous investment outside Phoenix, however, is his single-
handed support of Genetics Savings and Clone, a company that will allow
individuals to “bank” their own (or anyone else’s) genetic material for later
use, and Texas A&M University’s pet-cloning project. Sperling told Fortune
that his cloning support stemmed originally from his interest in preserving
his dog, Missy.12
In his autobiography, Sperling explains away such reversals and escapades:
he’s not a hypocrite; he’s a rebel. As Thomas Frank has pointed
out, businessmen of the past few decades have used such disassembling as
a powerful weapon in their battle for public approval: “The real object of
the ‘revolutionary’ management theory…[is] not efficiency or excellence
or even empowerment, but a far more abstract goal: the political and social
legitimacy of the corporation.”13 Talk of rebellion by billionaires requires
the belief that business for profit is some underground affair, and not the
default way of life for most of the world. If anything, Sperling’s role in
turning the production of knowledge into the production of profit is less
that of a lone rebel in hostile territory than that of a general leading a
conquering army toward the last enclave of stubborn holdouts against the
new regime.
And just as the enthusiasts of the “long boom” investment charade used
the language of dissent to disguise—or rehabilitate—greed and self-promotion,
Sperling’s rebel stance conceals a more conventional explanation for
his roundabout journey from traditional scholar and union activist to corporate
CEO. Upon examination, Sperling’s seemingly inexplicable shift
from AFT officer to union buster stems more from petty revenge than
from freethinking: He admits that being “voted out of the presidency of a
faculty union…cured me of my socialist sentiments in favor of nonprofits.”14
Sperling’s rejection of the liberal arts and his decision to root out of his
enterprise anything remotely resembling his glorious Berkeley days could
be a rebellion against traditional academe, but it also happens to be the
very foundation of Phoenix’s massive growth. The institution’s relentless
focus on employability makes Phoenix classes appealing to the corporations
that subsidize their employees’ classes and streamlines Phoenix’s operation.
If you don’t teach liberal arts, you don’t need a library. If you don’t
care about the learning that takes place outside of classrooms, you don’t
need student unions or student publications. Forty years after finishing his
“moveable feast,” Sperling is happy to serve fast food: “This is a corporation,
not a social entity,” Sperling told one interviewer. “Coming here is not
a rite of passage. We are not trying to develop their value systems or go in
for that ‘expand their minds’ bullshit.”15
His hammering on “accountability” after Phoenix’s infant years of suckling
at the federal teat is more rhetoric than reality. Though supporters of
for-profits often point to their “market-enforced” efficiency, few for-profit
institutions could afford to exist without Title IV monies. In 1999–2000,
proprietary institutions made up a whopping 35.4 percent of all institutions
participating in the Federal Pell Grant Program, and received about $945
million in Pell monies.16 Phoenix and other proprietary schools have spent
millions in the past few years in lobbying both Congress and legislatures to
keep those floodgates open, primarily by manipulating the accreditation
procedures that determine an institution’s eligibility for federal loan programs.
Phoenix is particularly motivated to loosen loan regulations: the
Education Department audit of the $339 million in loans and $9 million in
Pell Grants distributed by Phoenix in the mid-’90s found that the school
did not provide enough instructional time to qualify for much of the money
it had received in federal loans and grants. In addition, the university illegally
included cost of living when calculating need for students in correspondence
courses. In total, the department estimated that the university
disbursed about $54 million more than what students were entitled to
receive. (In its response, Phoenix officials asserted that their practices were
“good for [the university’s] students, for American business, for America’s
educational system, and for the global economy.”)17
Historically, proprietary institutions have met with resistance from what
they call “the higher education establishment” regarding accreditation. Thus,
Phoenix focuses its energy (and finances) on political influence as well as
economic growth, with no apologies from Sperling: “Yes, we use money to
get their attention—our American system of campaign finance gives us no
other alternative.”18 Thanks to this, Sperling claims, the Apollo Group and
Phoenix are “better known on the Hill than all but the state universities
and the nationally-known private institutions.”19 According to the Center
for Responsive Politics, in the 2000 election cycle alone the Apollo Group
made campaign contributions of more than $178,000 (a top contributor,
just behind the University of California, Harvard, Stanford, and Princeton).
In addition, the Career Colleges Association (a largely for-profit higher
education political action committee) donated more than $123,000, and
other for-profit higher education political action committee (PACs) forked
over around $190,000. Another comparison: Combined, the Apollo Group
and Career College Association PACs last year contributed more than
twice as much ($161,000) as the largest nonprofit donor, the American
Association of University Women, which gave its entire $66,000 to the
marginally less deregulation-happy Democrats.20 Compared with the multimillion-
dollar bundles brought in by defense contractors and drug companies,
the for-profit education sector is wading in the kiddie pool of political
payoff, but it’s getting a bargain.
In March, the Senate confirmed Sally Stroup, the Apollo Group’s top
lobbyist and a former congressional advisor on federal loan programs, as
the chief higher education policymaker in the Department of Education.
Stroup advised the chair of the Post-Secondary Education Committee from
1993 to 2001 and was instrumental in helping to draft the 1998
reauthorization of the Higher Education Act. The 1998 reauthorization
reversed many of the harsher restrictions on for-profit schools (making it
easier for them to appeal penalization on loan defaults), eliminated some of
the more grueling aspects of the accreditation process (making surprise
visits optional, and no longer requiring inspectors to visit every branch of
a campus), redefined “institutions of higher education” to include for-profit
schools rather than defining them as a separate category, and created a
special proprietary schools liaison with the Education Department, a privilege
previously reserved for historically black universities and community
colleges.21
Secretary of Education Ronald Paige made a less high-profile but more
influential appointment in 2001 when he gave Laura Palmer Noone, the
president of the University of Phoenix, a place on the National Advisory
Committee on Institutional Quality and Integrity. This committee makes
recommendations to the secretary regarding changes in regional and national
accreditation policies and standards, including those regulations that
determine an institution’s eligibility for Title IV programs. The Higher
Education Act is due for its next review and reauthorization in 2003.
Given his success in manipulating the system to his advantage, Sperling’s
rebel stance is in fact the squarest behavior imaginable, fitting quite
comfortably into the paneled club-room atmosphere of big business. Still,
as amusing as his contradictions are, John Sperling would be of no interest
at all if his tactics and bloviations had no effect or if Phoenix were just a roadside oddity. But it’s not. The success of Phoenix has transformed the
maverick oddball into an influential model. Nonprofits are increasingly
looking to for-profits for clues as to how to run their own institutions.
The Creeping For-Profit Ethos:
From Phoenix to the World
Clearly, nonprofits aren’t trying to become profitable, but administrators at
traditional institutions have now turned to the corporate model as a solution
to the age-old and tax-status-independent problems of budgets and cash flow.
Things have changed since the University of Chicago dropped its football
team or an administration approached wealthy alumni for a generous donation.
The difference is twofold: when it comes to making cuts, athletics are
less likely to be on the chopping block than departments and programs. In
1998, for example, the Board of Higher Education in Massachusetts suggested
“establishing a program productivity review that requires campuses
to eliminate, or provide a compelling reason for retaining, academic programs
that have fewer than a minimum threshold of graduates per year for
a period of three years.” As the authors of the report explained, “This will
reduce expenditures.”22 The group also “urged a reduction in ‘public service’
projects that have little to do with students or teaching”—a sweeping definition
that could mean anything from limiting student volunteer efforts to
reducing community studies not financed by outside donors.23 (It should be
noted that these sorts of programs are intended to develop young people’s
civic sensibilities over their predilection toward self-interest.) And when it
comes to bringing more revenue in, administrators are willing to sell more
than just the name of a gymnasium—they’ll trade a college’s resources and
reputation. In 1997, the University of Wisconsin began a joint, for-profit
venture with the software firm Lotus to sell Wisconsin degrees worldwide.24
The always inventive Massachusetts Board of Higher Education touted its
“collaborations with business and industry,” noting that “[a]ll campuses have
developed alliances with local and regional business and industry to provide
employee training and development opportunities, as well as research support.”
25 A harbinger of this coziness emerged in the late 1980s, when the
University of Rochester caved to the demands of a major donor, Eastman
Kodak Co., to rescind its acceptance of a graduate student employed by Fuji
Photo Film, Inc., a major competitor of Kodak.26
Other specific instances of nonprofits appropriating for-profit techniques
abound. Take, for instance, Ohio State University’s “selective investment”
program, in which departments compete for million-dollar “prizes” by way
of U.S. News and World Report rankings.27 More commonly, schools simply
demand that teachers offer “blockbuster” or “heavy draw” courses like
those related to professional sports or other “entertaining” subjects. Such
moves resemble the financial discipline that governs Phoenix’s policy of
developing courses only for which there is high demand. Numerous
universities have started using their control over course content to license
and then sell courseware to for-profit online entities. This sort of arrangement
is a familiar pattern at Phoenix, where tightly structured, centrally developed
lesson plans allow Phoenix’s administration to dictate how a professor
spends time, right down to fifteen-minute intervals, and where copyrights
keep hostage what knowledge those plans may hold. What’s more,
streamlined courses are easier to shop out to low-paid adjunct professors.
There are dozens of more familiar ways that nonprofits have come to
resemble for-profits, including the hiring of private companies to manage
such capital-intensive areas as cafeteria service, campus housing, and college
bookstores. At least the University of Phoenix has specific, logical reasons
for pursuing such schemes: They centralize course development to take
advantage of mass production. They direct funds to popular programs
because no one goes to Phoenix to learn linguistics or art history, anyway.
And collaborating with corporations makes sense because corporations are,
for all intents and purposes, their real customers. Why have nonprofits
picked up these habits? Why, for instance, did the Colorado higher education
system decide in 1999 that “instead of the university deciding what ought
to be taught, professors and chancellors will listen to what the chief executive
officers say,” and require “every college in the state” to compile “a list of
technology courses it offers”? These will be “given to company executives,
who will tell the educators where they fall short.”28 Why has Tulane University
president Scott S. Cowen spent the last few years hammering away at
shared governance, lamenting that it “stand[s] in the way of quick, effective
decision-making”?29
To be sure, part of the motivation to be more like for-profits is simply
about the bottom line: adjuncts are cheaper, and centralized courses—and
not having to pay professors to develop them—are cheaper, too. The sad
news is that many students seem to want it that way. Indeed, research such
as the annual freshman survey conducted by the Higher Education Research
Institute at the University of California at Los Angeles provides sobering
evidence that whether or not students actually attend for-profit institutions,
they seem to share the same values. In response to the 2001 survey,
students ranked their “life goals”: more than 75 percent said “being very
well-off financially” was “very important.” Toward the bottom of the list:
“influencing the political structure” (16 percent) and “writing original works”
(13 percent).30 Everywhere young people turn in today’s culture, they get
the message that money is the true measure of a life. Russell Jacoby, in
Dogmatic Wisdom, cites a classic example: Students who apply for credit
cards with “humanities” listed as their area of interest are turned down;
when they reapply with “finance” as their interest, they get the card.31
What they do with the card suggests that it is not the making of money
that concerns them, but the spending of it: UCLA’s survey revealed that
21.4 percent had overspent their budgets and 16.7 percent had what they
termed “excessive credit card debt”—this at a time when the average credit
debt of American college students is $2,748.32
“Financially rewarding” or “career oriented” do not sound like hallmarks
of a good education to a traditional academic’s ear. But today’s students
operate from the profit motive, and it makes sense for their schools to do
so as well. DeVry’s Ruch explains, “The more traditional, abstract notion
of learning for its own sake and the idea of cultivating knowledge that
appears to lack utilitarian value does not resonate with a growing number
of today’s students and their families.”33 Never mind that few college
freshmen are equipped to decide what may or may not lack utilitarian
value; for-profits simply give students what the students think they need.
As Sperling has said, “Academia simply doesn’t understand this. They call
it McEducation. What we do is every bit as much education as the Greek
system that served as the model for the modern university. Greek educators
prepared people for life. We prepare people for a life of work.”34
And in the terrible symmetry of the market, the loop is completed:
what the students want, well, for-profits will do almost anything to maintain
the illusion that that’s what they’re providing. We all know how well the
consumer approach has maintained high-quality standards in, say, financial
markets. In a sense, for-profit institutions like the University of Phoenix
are the Enrons of higher education: built on a bubble of good feeling,
sustained by a siphoning off of public goods and monies. It is possible to
move too quickly in response to demand, and therefore teach badly but
“efficiently.” Proprietary institutions call this “pleasing the customer” and,
next to the flipped-collar nonchalance of the for-profit rebel, it’s the most
common explanation put forward by their fans for the success of places
like Phoenix. Catering to the practical needs of students undoubtedly appeals
to the working adults that make up the overwhelming majority of Phoenix
students, and it’s unlikely that it actively harms their education: You can
learn as well at 8 P.M. as at 9 A.M. The assumed sensibilities of the sacred
customer justify the more ideological decisions of for-profits as well.
As DeVry’s Ruch sees it, he is simply empowering students: “It is
ultimately the students who set the standard for what is appropriate and
acceptable in terms of freedom of expression.” Why? “This philosophy is
grounded in the standard customer-service orientation of any successful
for-profit venture.”35 Phoenix in particular takes pride in dismissing professors
who score poorly on student evaluations. As Phoenix administrators see it,
pleasing students should determine the “eligibility [emphasis added] of faculty
members to provide instruction.”36 For-profits rush new courses to market,
eliminate old ones, employ part-time professionals as teachers, and accept
credit for “life experiences,” including divorce—all for the sake of the
customer.37
The “Costs” of For-Profit Education
These policies probably do please customers. Whether or not they add up
to an education worth the investment is another matter. (Professors, for
example, often report that their own sense of pedagogic mission gets steadily
diluted as crowd-pleasing curricula create subordinate pressures to “get in
the sandbox” with their eager-to-be-entertained charges, padding syllabi
with movies, rock criticism, and various dogmatic interpretations of pop-
cult transgression.) To define academic success as what the student is happy
with risks not so much a low-quality education (though that is a possibility)
but rather a narrow education, one focused on the here and now, “applicable
skills,” and conventional wisdom. But treating the student as a consumer
necessarily turns education into a product—something consumable with benefits
that are immediate and gratifying: a soda, a movie, a pornographic website.
Defenders of the for-profit faith say that giving students what they want
ensures a good education, but what they actually mean is that students “get
what they came for, and the institution is assured continued growth, ongoing
market demand, and profitability.”38
Imagine running a government this way. It would lack revenues because
citizen-consumers will have demanded an end to all taxation. (A not-toodistant
possibility, really.) This kind of thinking is reminiscent of the student
council candidate whose platform consisted of “longer lunch periods” and
“a better prom.” And just as a longer lunch period won’t get students any
closer to understanding algebra, so offering high-demand degrees doesn’t
get students closer to actually understanding and participating in their world.
One of the hardest lessons to learn is knowledge isn’t necessarily what you
want to know—in the sense that, well, we’d be happier not knowing about
Rwandan genocide or the Dresden firebombing or the Nixon administration.
Education as a product means, essentially, teaching only what students
want to hear, whether that’s how to program in C++ or that everything is
just fine, don’t worry your pretty little head, nothing needs to change. A
degree in Microsoft network administration may get you a job, but when
we talk of the “utility” of an education, it must mean something beyond
that: it must mean gaining hard-won understanding; it must mean the
ability to question the world around you. It must mean hearing things you
don’t agree with and knowing things that upset you.
Yet nonprofits have already accepted at least the language of customer
satisfaction. In addition to the rampant grade inflation that is a hallmark of
for- and nonprofits alike, nonprofits pay attention to the desires of students
when they trumpet graduate salaries and point to students’ “return on
educational investment.”39 Once fluent in this dialect, it can only become
easier for traditional schools to accept for-profits’ logic of education-ascommodity
and to fully embrace the techniques they’ve taken tentative steps
toward. Freemarketers would welcome this and all the “enforced efficiency”
that would follow, but in this race to the bottom, existing for-profits will
always win. Yes, they do have a head start—but they’re also cheating.
Why Not-For-Profits Will Fail,
or the Underbelly of Market Logic
Of course, they’re cheating the customer—both in a moral and a fiduciary
sense that might alarm even today’s business-savvy student. For-profits’
proponents often point to their respect for their student/consumers as a
benefit that nonprofits are not in a position to offer. Professors at traditional
schools, they say, “fear…the loss of traditional authority, as well as
the growing demand for greater accountability in their work as teachers”
that would come with a customer focus. All this talk of customer service,
however, is belied by one simple fact: The customer is being ripped off.
On the for-profit side, administrators say their students choose the stripped-
down, sped-up, frill-free education they offer because students don’t want to
pay for the cafeterias, dorm rooms, and sports teams that drive up the cost
of tuition at other schools. But those students aren’t saving their own money;
they’re allowing proprietary schools to charge them for amenities the schools
aren’t providing. Traditional education is expensive, and in part that’s because
of the frills, student groups and insurance coverage and the like, but students
at traditional schools are rarely charged for those frills. As educational
economist Gordon C.Winston has shown, a combination of scholarships,
grants, and simple discounting allows the average nonprofit to subsidize
students to the tune of about $8,800 a year. That is, an education that costs
(on average) $12,500 to produce is being sold to students for $3,700. Breaking
the nonprofit group into private and public institutions doesn’t dilute the
subsidy much, though the end price to the student differs.40
Phoenix, on the other hand, offers no such discount—neither do most
other for-profits—because charging at least as much as the education costs
to produce is what makes them who they are: Price-cost=profit. Traditional
institutions operate at a loss: public universities sell a $10,150 education
for $1,230; private schools sell a $15,310 education for $6,640.41 By contrast,
the University of Phoenix generates a net return of $101 per student
annually.42 And when one considers that the cost of a Phoenix education—
$8,000—is about the same as tuition at a private institution with comparable
programs, it all becomes clear: Students get much less than they pay for,
and that’s not even considering the quality of education they get.43
Overcharging like this works because of the intimate relationships
proprietary schools (especially Phoenix) enjoy with their clients, the
employers of their students. These partnerships are so intertwined that the
institutions basically become the exclusive providers of job training. In fact,
Phoenix has created several business partnerships in which employees can
take classes at a corporate training center and then apply those toward a
University of Phoenix degree. Some nonprofit institutions have made similar
deals, but not with the enthusiasm of Phoenix, which will accept corporate
training as credit for up to 15 percent of a student’s degree.44 John Sears,
Apollo’s vice president, argues that such a deal is a natural fit for employers
concerned with getting the quickest education possible for their students. In
such a situation, he told one reporter, “Which model makes more sense:
the traditional four-year university, which is essentially a model of inefficiency?
Or a virtual education machine like the University of Phoenix, which brings
a total quality management discipline to academic cost control?”45
Such cooperation with employers raises some obvious concerns. For one:
Is job training really education? The president and chief executive officer of
the Apollo Group, Jorge Klor de Alva, says simply that “the lines between
education and training are blurring.” But it would seem that one distinction
remains clear: Mere training—especially training that’s designed so that you
can, as de Alva says, “take what you learn and apply it to work immediately”—
is poor preparation for the inevitable moment when the technology improves,
methods change, and your training becomes out of date.46
By providing just-in-time education that’s designed to exact specification
of what employers need right now, Phoenix has put the finishing touches on
its model of education-as-consumer-product. Phoenix has built planned
obsolescence into knowledge, and made an education as disposable as paper
plates and Ikea furniture. This works brilliantly as a business plan. What
are you going to do when your training becomes out of date? Well, go out
and buy some more, of course. If you don’t, your employer can simply
buy a new worker, with more cutting-edge content.
This market logic also works to discipline students as they pursue their
training—all to the detriment of free speech and thought. Already, Sperling
justifies the absence of liberal arts courses at Phoenix by saying the employers
who subsidize students “won’t support Greeks and Romans.”47 There are
surely other subjects that employers would rather keep their staff from
studying: Would ExxonMobil want its people studying the effect of
greenhouse gases? Would IBM want a programmer to learn about his
company’s ties to the Nazis?
Considering these rather problematic possibilities, it’s unlikely that
nonprofits will take the exact same steps as for-profits, but it’s worth exploring
what might happen if they did. Could a nonprofit become as cost-effective as
the University of Phoenix, wiping out residential features, libraries, and such?
It seems impossible at a large state school, but what about a small private
commuter college? Or a community college? These two types of institutions
are Phoenix’s real competitors and are schools that stand to lose the most
students when Phoenix or a company like it moves into town. They also
have the fewest campus amenities to begin with. But should they go the cost-
cutting route, they’d be faced with a problem that proprietary schools always
escape: once you cut student services, who provides them? This is the secret
of for-profit education. While Phoenix relies upon the federal government
much more than its leaders would ever admit, it also gets a free ride on the
backs of nonprofit institutions.
A huge chunk of the University of Phoenix’s savings, for instance, comes
out of its insistence that a “virtual library”—a collection of nine thousand or
so electronic journals—is a reasonable substitute for the real thing. The head
of Phoenix’s “learning research center” has said that books are “far less
critical than they were 30 years ago when I was in college.”48 Of course,
books are just as central as they’ve ever been, but they’re also about as
expensive. Last year, Harvard spent $22 million on its library of 14 million
volumes; at the low end, tiny McMaster Divinity College spent $854,000 on
its 1.8 million volume library. The average university research library contains 3.6 million volumes and costs about $1.9 million a year.49 When the University
of Phoenix negotiated its way into New Jersey—where strict accreditation
standards had stalled it—the school overcame the state’s provision that all
institutions of higher education have a library of at least fifty thousand volumes
by purchasing access to New Jersey City University’s 245,000 volume library
in exchange for five computers and shared access to a suite of business
databases—a deal worth about $25,000 to the public university.50
Places such as Phoenix can get away with eliminating libraries in most
cases because their students can use public ones, sometimes the libraries of
the very institutions that have lost students to for-profits. Jacqueline Raphel
and Shelia Tobias have reported that “Phoenix frequently piggybacks on
the ‘competition.’” According to Raphel and Tobias, students from Phoenix’s
Santa Teresa campus in New Mexico, located immediately across the border
from the University of Texas at El Paso, use the public school’s library
resources to such an extent that “reference librarians sometimes have to
ask the Phoenix students to step aside so that the UTEP students’ needs
can be accommodated.”51
This leeching off public resources extends the for-profit labor model, as
well. Phoenix’s practice of hiring only part-time professors who are actively
working in the field they teach allows it to take advantage of human capital
investment made elsewhere: at the universities that support full-time teachers
who train the next generation of scholars. This generous transfer-credit policy
allows it to do the same with students—essentially inflating its graduation and
enrollment statistics without actually having to educate every student.
Traditional schools remain caught in an unyielding conundrum: There has to
be a first place where people learn—where, for example, students can get the M.A. that’s the only requirement to teach at Phoenix. A traditional college
literally can’t afford to save money the way Phoenix does.
What the Future Holds
This longer range view shows that pursuing corporate models could be the
end of higher education as we know it rather than, as some insist, the next
step forward. However, even the oldest universities sometimes don’t look
much past tomorrow, and at its present pace, the for-profit approach seems
destined to triumph. It may not be that the University of Phoenix is, as
Sperling has said, in commissar-like fashion, “moving inexorably eastward,”
but the sleight-of-hand policy changes that inch nonprofits evercloser to a
corporate form may mean that most traditional schools become for-profit
in everything but tax status.
The myth of social mobility notwithstanding, American higher education
has always been poised to split in two: on the one hand, expensive, elite
private schools for those who can afford them (and the handful of gentrifying
“public ivies” like Michigan and Berkeley); on the other, resource-strapped,
poorly funded public institutions for everyone else. The rise of the for-
profit has merely exacerbated this divide, precisely because in the for-
profit future, only the richest private universities may thrive. The social
capital afforded by an Ivy League diploma is worth protecting (why dilute
the brand with branch campuses of Yale™?), and selling at a premium. The
humanities will become (some might argue they’ll simply continue to be)
an affluent affectation, like $600 Prada bike messenger bags.
The less well off schools will be forced to compete against the elites, and
will either run themselves into the ground doing so, or will adopt all the
for-profit tactics that they can, perhaps even chucking libraries, dorms,
departments (what’s the percentage in a classics department?). Another
strategy would take them to for-profit status by half measures: they’ll charge
more for “low-demand” courses, offer discounts to students who give up
their library privileges, create an airline-esque class system in which “first
class” students get more comfortable chairs and better computers in
exchange for a premium tuition. And then who knows? If an institution
acts like a corporation, it becomes a corporation.
Those who wish to see higher education maintain its relative freedom
and accessibility can’t rely on the incongruity of education being treated as
a consumer product to make their case, or use traditional institutions’ moral
superiority to attract students. With continuing education becoming
something of a political jackpot (like helping children or the elderly, who
could possibly be against continuing education?), for-profit lobbyists are
positioned to push their clients as the ideal providers of continuing education,
and therefore the likely recipients of whatever federal or state aid is available.
And with state aid will come more acceptance of proprietary institutions.
Greater acceptance, in turn, will accelerate the continued erosion of regional
and national accreditation standards.
As mentioned above, for-profit lobbyists are already busy negotiating
changes to the regional and national accreditation systems, making it easier
for them to compete with traditional schools. Lobbyists go state by state to
check the power of state legislatures over regional accrediting bodies. Regional
accrediting standards are often flexible, but state laws can toughen—or
weaken—them. That is, especially if unions and organizations like the
American Association of University Professors exert pressure on them.
Even against counterpressure, the for-profit logic is bulldozing ahead.
One proposal would guarantee accreditation to any school that is able to
prove that a certain percentage of its graduates had obtained jobs. Clearly,
proprietary schools, with their close corporate relationships, would be the
institutions to benefit from this. Another change would allow for-profits to
hire less-qualified and thus cheaper instructors. Traditional institutions must
have a minimum number of professors with Ph.D.’s in order to grant
degrees in any particular field. For-profit lobbyists would like to reduce this
minimum number for their clients.
For-profits would also love to dip their fingers into the pot of state loans
and grants that until now local legislatures have been reluctant to give
them. Proprietary administrators argue, as the executive vice president of
ITT Technical Institutes has said, “If we’re good enough to pass state
standards, to meet the bar where states raised it, then our students should
have fair standing to access taxpayer dollars to finance their education.”52
Critics point out that this would essentially amount to corporate welfare.
As with federal grants and loans, the students who receive such scholarships
would simply be the conduits for the money going from taxpayers to
institutional profits.
There are changes that are more seriously afoot at the national level,
where the Education Department creates guidelines for all regional
accreditation and sets up the requirement for federal loan eligibility. For-
profits would like to eliminate a federal loan eligibility requirement that
students receive at least twelve hours of in-class instruction a week to be
considered full time. They also want to abolish a federal law that prohibits
colleges from providing bonuses or other incentive payments to admissions
officers or financial-aid administrators for enrolling students. According to
the Chronicle of Higher Education, lobbyists for for-profits say “the law does
not allow employees to be financially rewarded for exceptional performance.”
That is sort of the point, though, as the regulation was created in response
to recruiters from diploma mills, who earned such bonuses by enrolling
clearly unqualified students out of unemployment centers. The students,
who generally flunked out, were simply a means by which proprietary
schools received federal loans.
But the most important of the for-profit initiatives is the push to revise
Education Department rules stipulating that at least 10 percent of a forprofit’s
income must come from sources other than federal aid. Once this
restriction is lifted, the proprietary schools are in a position to siphon off a
much larger portion of the aid available to all schools—another blow to the
viability of resource-poor colleges. Phoenix and its cohorts are in essence
pushing for the deregulation of higher education, and it could have the
same disastrous results that followed the deregulation of savings and loans,
telecom businesses, and airlines.
The best response, then, is to push to maintain and strengthen higher
education regulation at the local, state, and federal levels. Ideally, one could
put an end to federal and state student aid for students at for-profits, perhaps
legislate a definition of what a college degree is, including a minimum number
of credits in various disciplines. One could argue that such a policy is akin to
the national standardized tests that are being proposed at the K-12 level.
Still, imagine how outraged the happily consumerist students who
responded to the UCLA survey would be if they were suddenly held
accountable for their educations. Then again, realism enters the picture: these
young people don’t vote. (The UCLA study also found this class to have the
least interest in politics in years.)53 Imagine, as well, the response of capitalist-
friendly courts to a restraint-of-trade challenge that for-profits would inevitably
bring in response to any harsh regulations actually enacted. So what looks on
paper to be the most promising path to curbing for-profits’ growth is also the
steepest one. In any event, legislation will not stanch what is essentially a
seismic cultural shift. To counter the predominance of for-profit education,
nonprofit schools need to assert the autonomy of their mission—while also
introducing important changes in their own institutional culture.
Traditional universities could stop competing with for-profits by trying
to be like them and instead look at why proprietary schools appeal to
students. Understanding this appeal doesn’t mandate mimicking the for-
profit mantra of pursuing customer satisfaction at every level. Schools
could compete with the practical advantages of for-profits: year-round
campuses, schedules convenient to nontraditional students (who are,
statistically speaking, actually very traditional). There are ways to moderately
accelerate programs without losing their spirit.
More radically, faculty at traditional schools could make a preemptive
strike at tenure. Already decreasing at an alarming rate, the number of
tenured positions is heading toward zero—not because tenure as an institution
is being abolished, but because it’s eroding. Universities replace tenure-
track jobs with full-time adjuncts, and tenured professors continue to see
academic freedom as a reward rather than as a right. For faculties to take
the initiative and actively seek a replacement for tenure through collective
bargaining would benefit professors at traditional schools by strengthening
their power to maintain the standards of liberal education. A contract that
protected academic freedom could also extend that right to adjuncts,
librarians, teaching assistants, and faculty at for-profit schools, for whom
tenure has rarely existed. The power of an entire academic community
would be something to reckon with. The bond that would be formed between
teachers at for-profits and nonprofits could strengthen both their positions
at their respective institutions, and break down the stereotypes (of being
elitist and condescending, of being poorly educated and unqualified) that
currently keep them apart.
Still, a realist might ask, what about the students who just want jobs?
What about the students’ parents, who think academics exist in ivory towers
and come down only to indoctrinate their children into communism,
feminism, and same-sex romance? What about the policymakers who look
at universities and see nothing but the red ink flowing out of them? These
are obstacles that can be addressed only by deep cultural shifts. We need
changes in our political culture that articulate wider civic needs over shortterm
benefits. For instance, what about a wider discussion about universal military
service—the sort that would draft all young people, no matter their income
or connections, and that would induce a much more realistic debate about
the use of armed forces abroad? What about requiring, as some of the
original advocates for AmeriCorps proposed, mandatory community service
as a means of educating young people for the responsibilities of active
citizenship? We need to have political discussions in this country that challenge
us to become something more than just self-interested individuals. In this
case, we need a higher education policy that emphasizes the need for
wellrounded, thoughtful citizens.
No comments:
Post a Comment